Thứ Tư, 31 tháng 5, 2017

Waching daily May 31 2017

if you're trying to find out if your channel is doing successful but those

analytics aren't making a lot of sense speak for yourself

stay tuned because I have a new secret tool that is completely free yeah I said

free and that's coming up next hi my name is Danielle branch and I'm going to

be your hostess with the mostess for the next few minutes so buckle up baby

because you haven't seen a video quite like this one if you want to find out

how to be engaging be fun and be different and maybe some tools that are

going to help you in your YouTube career they consider subscribing down below and

ring that bell if you want to be notified the next time I have a video

come out so today we're going to be talking about a brand new tool that is

going to help you figure out how well your channel is doing and how to make it

better that tool is called morning pain so morning fame is a fantastic tool that

tells you all sorts of things on how each video helped you be able to

increase your subscribers your watch time and your views but best of all it's

free yes I said it look free2go can also join morning veins

it is by invitation only so you're only going to be able to get it through this

link now here's the cool part no matter what stage your channel is in you can

also use morning vein I've been using it for a little over a month now and I

don't know how I lived without this no matter if you are brand-new to

you tube or you've been here for a little while morning same is for you

here's what morning same briefly can do for you every single time that you

upload a video you're going to be able to figure out how well it's performing

within the first very critical 72 hours every week you're going to be able to

see things such as if that video helped you increase the quality of your channel

if it didn't really help you too much or if it didn't help at all

wouldn't that be really helpful information to know if the people that

are watching your videos if they enjoyed one video more than another many of us

don't understand the analysis that are listed there inside of YouTube our

smartypants is do well not everyone is a mathematician or you know someone that

knows Greek we want it in plain English something easy to understand and that is

what morning thing to do so not only is it going to tell you generally where you

are it's also going to tell you how you can help so if you want to get started

with morning same like I said there's going to be a link down in the

description where you can also sign up as well you want to learn how to be

engaging be fun and be different and maybe how do you actually use morning

Fame go ahead and subscribe down below and ring that Bell so you can be

notified the next time of video comes out chances are I'm going to go and do a

morning thing so over the course of the next few videos I am going to be taking

you into a deep dive on what morning thing does how it can help you and some

of the things that you can see so until then I will see you in the next video

For more infomation >> Free Growth Hacking Tool For Your Channel - Duration: 4:02.

-------------------------------------------

Adam Sandler up for an Oscar?!?! * And 12 more true weird news stories! #DDWN - Duration: 6:58.

From DailyDoseOfWeirdNews.com, I'm Darren Marlar and this is your Daily Dose of Weird

News!

This episode is brought to you by the audiobook, "The Black Eyed Kids" by G. Michael Vasey,

narrated by Darren Marlar.

Hear a free sample of this terrifying audiobook at DailyDoseOfWeirdNews.com.

A free navigation app (from Karta GPS) now features the option of getting your directions

from celebrity voices including Bill Clinton.

***(As Bill Clinton) "Turn right up ahead, there's a great no-tell motel you should

check out..."

Ariana Grande announced that she's going to return to Manchester to perform a benefit

concert for all the bombing victims.

***While there she plans to lick all the croissants and say she hates the British.

The Trump Soho hotel in New York City is planning to make staff layoffs.

Everybody sing: "Soho, Soho, it's out-of-work you go...

"

In Utah, 39-year-old Tori Lee Castillo is facing child abuse charges in what witnesses

are describing as an appalling incident.

She allegedly locked her two children, ages 2 and 5, in the trunk of her car while she

left to shop at a local Walmart.

The Riverdale City Police Department got a call Thursday after a witness reported seeing

Castillo put her kids in the trunk.

Utah police said, "The small children ... began making noise and moving frantically, causing

the vehicle to shake."

Fortunately, several good Samaritans saw it happen and ran to aid the kids.

Police say, "Those good Samaritans coached the 5-year-old on how to open the trunk using

an emergency latch.

One witness said, "I was shocked, I was shaken, and I was mad."

Castillo was arrested as soon as she returned to her car.

***Personally, I don't think justice was served unless the police stuck her in the

trunk of the patrol car to take her to jail.

Police in Edmonton, Alberta, Canada are trying to find the thieves who made off with two

semi-trailers full of more than $160,000 worth of beer.

The trucks have been recovered but the beer is still missing.

***Get the bloodhounds sniffing for a suburban brewery and you might close this case.

A Florida woman was arrested for assaulting her ex with an order of pork fried rice.

***Others throw rice at you when you get married, your ex throws rice at you after you're

married... is marriage secretly sponsored by Uncle Ben's?

A couple of neighbors in Manchester who can't get along felt it was important to waste the

time of local police.

But this was no ordinary neighbor's dispute.

The scenario was shared by officers who tweeted: "Today we've dealt with a neighbor dispute

where a dead goldfish covered in cheese has been posted through a letterbox.

I kid you not."

***Just when you thought there were no original crimes left to commit.

Ice cream giant Ben and Jerry's has come up with an interesting protest supporting gay

rights and marriage equality in Australia.

Saying, "Love comes in all flavors," the company's 26 stores in Australia have "banned" serving

of two scoops of the same kind of ice cream until same-sex marriage is legalized in the

country.

In a statement, Ben and Jerry's asks customers to imagine how furious being denied a double

scoop of their favorite flavor would make them.

"But this doesn't even begin to compare to how furious you would be if you were told

you were not allowed to marry the person you love," it adds.

***Hey guys, you do realize that people can just go to another ice cream store to get

two scoops of their favorite ice cream, right?

Instead of ending a ban on a same-sex marriage, all you're doing is creating a ban on Ben

& Jerry's.

Disney says that threat of cyber thieves stealing a copy of the latest Pirates of the Caribbean

movie and holding it for ransom... was apparently a hoax.

***Although after reading some of the reviews, they might've been better off if it had

been stolen... and never released.

Two South Carolina men were charged with harassing an alligator after forcing the creature to

drink beer.

The men were on a dirt road (near Hardeeville) when they saw the young alligator crossing

the road.

The duo picked it up and poured beer down its throat before releasing it.

It later swam away in a nearby pond.

The two men uploaded photos of their antics to social media, which is how officers from

the South Carolina Department of Natural Resources got wind of their crime.

***Maybe we should go back to those Obama smartphones for everyone so all criminals

have an equal opportunity to incriminate themselves.

Brace yourself -- Adam Sandler's latest movie, "The Meyerowitz Stories," is actually getting

some Oscar buzz.

***Never thought you'd see Adam Sandler and the word Oscar in the same sentence, did you?

In Massachusetts, Orlando Melendez got some bad news.

A judge has denied his request to juggle during his trial to show jurors he was just clowning

around when he allegedly tried to rob a convenience store.

Yes - juggle!

Melendez has pleaded not guilty to charges he used a toy gun to try to rob a convenience

store in December.

The 20-year-old man, who is representing himself, asked that he be allowed to juggle three wads

of paper for 20 seconds to show jurors that the alleged attempted robbery was a misunderstanding

because he's a professional clown.

***Honestly, with the news of the past couple of years, telling people you are a clown is

in no way going to be help your case with a jury.

Now that the FBI investigation has begun to focus on Jared Kushner he has been told to

lay low.

***White House lawyers have hidden him in a secure undisclosed location next to Kellyanne

Conway.

The Marlar House mobile app is now available – and it's FREE!

Find me on Facebook, Twitter and Instagram, watch Marlar House YouTube videos, check out

the t-shirts, mugs, audiobooks and other stuff in the Marlar House store, see what's in

my blog, and more… all in one app!

And it's FREE for IOS and ANDROID users!

Download it now at MarlarHouse.com/MOBILE!

If you like this video, please give it a thumbs up – and be sure to subscribe if you want

to see more!

And click that little bell icon next to the subscribe button to be notified when I post

new videos!

And if you're already an official Weirdo, please share this video on your own social

media.

Find even more weird news that I didn't have time for on the Facebook page at DailyDoseOfWeirdNews.com.

I'm Darren Marlar…

I'll see you next time, Weirdos!

For more infomation >> Adam Sandler up for an Oscar?!?! * And 12 more true weird news stories! #DDWN - Duration: 6:58.

-------------------------------------------

Lucius Believes Hugo Strange Has An Antidote For The Virus | Season 3 Ep. 21 | GOTHAM - Duration: 1:41.

- An antidote?

Lucius, I could kiss your face.

Before you do that, I don't actually have the formula.

But there is an antidote, that's what you're saying?

I was going through the papers you recovered

from the Owl leader's house.

They suggest that while Strange was working to weaponize

the Tetch virus, he was also working on a parallel project

tailoring different anti-viral agents to his own ends.

Strange was designing an antidote.

That makes sense.

The Court was careful to protect its own.

They would want to safeguard.

We need to talk to Strange.

Is he still here or has he been moved?

Uh, well, when you were buried in the coffin

and the city was about to be virus bombed,

some decisions had to be made.

Harvey.

I told Alfred to question Strange.

In exchange for him telling us where

the bombing was going to go down, Alfred let Strange walk.

Yes, I'm blaming it on the butler.

[dramatic music]

Strange is weasel.

He tried to get as far away from this as possible.

Union Station is shut down.

Downtown train station's our best bet.

Wait up.

Harvey.

Lucius, I know what you're going to say, all right?

He can handle this.

Hell, Barnes had the virus for weeks before anyone knew.

But I was going to say, from all

I see here, Strange's virus is an accelerated

version of the Tetch virus.

Why do you think people are reacting so quickly?

Gordon isn't going to be able to fight this for long.

Well, we'll just have to wait and see, huh?

You keep working on that antidote.

For more infomation >> Lucius Believes Hugo Strange Has An Antidote For The Virus | Season 3 Ep. 21 | GOTHAM - Duration: 1:41.

-------------------------------------------

PAW Patrol toy review for kids| PAW Patrol toys with Dump Trucks and Bulldozer| Trucks for children - Duration: 10:08.

PAW Patrol toy review for kids, PAW Patrol toys with Dump Trucks and Bulldozer, Trucks for children

On this video we will show to you PAW Patrol toy unboxing, and play with them.

For more infomation >> PAW Patrol toy review for kids| PAW Patrol toys with Dump Trucks and Bulldozer| Trucks for children - Duration: 10:08.

-------------------------------------------

Social Selection in Education and its Consequences for Mobility - Duration: 1:40:30.

(pensive, midtempo music)

- Hi, everybody.

I want to welcome you to this wonderful occasion,

a very special occasion.

This is the first in the Lee Rainwater lecture series.

My name is Tim Smeeding; I'll tell you who I am in a minute,

but first of all I want to thank Janet and Mary Waters

for doing the organization.

If you want anything organized, get Janet,

and if you want to do anything at Harvard

and have the facilities and everything ready, go to Mary.

I know all the life lessons,

and her staff, Janet will mention.

I want to thank our good friend and colleague Robert Erikson

for coming to speak, and the rest of you

for coming out in the rain.

Thank you very much, and I hope you enjoy it.

What we're gonna have now is a 30-minute short program

of remembrance of Lee.

I must say, I met Lee in 1983 and he said,

"Some people said you'd be crazy enough to go over

"to Luxembourg and try and build this data project,"

and I said, "Well, we'll give it a try,"

and for the next 23 years, we built something

called the Luxembourg Income Study.

Along the way, I got to know him, his brilliance, his quiet.

You will hear somebody say, if they don't say:

"Lee was the brains and Tim was the engine,"

pretty much, of LIS.

Anyway, we built this Luxembourg Income Study,

which we've given to Janet now,

and Janet has done amazingly well,

has built it up, has two offices.

She's got Paul Krugman on her team,

she's got Branko Milanovic, she's got 62 countries,

and Phil is really happy, so there.

But Lee was also a co-author.

He was a father figure to me.

When my dad passed away in '88,

Lee and I had long talks about that.

He was a tutor, and he taught me to drink wine, not beer;

I'm always grateful for him for that,

(audience chuckles)

and two years ago, my university gave me

a WARF named distinguished professorship,

and I could pick the name of anybody I wanted.

So me, the economist and public-policy type, decided

that I would be the Lee Rainwater Distinguished Professor

of Public Policy and Economics, and it reminds me everyday

when I look at that little signature block

how much Lee meant to me and how close I was to him.

So we're really happy you could be here.

I made my quota.

Jan, am I on time?

Good, phew.

Now, I want to introduce, for those of you

who don't know it, this is Carol Rainwater,

who was always Lee's partner.

She would even come to Luxembourg now and then,

you can see her in the t-shirts up there,

(laughs) and dressed better than that.

She wants to greet you all as well,

and then we'll go from there.

Carol.

- I didn't realize that I would have an excuse

for not being able to talk well by being hit in the head.

(audience laughs)

And instead, I was gonna tell you

that if there weren't so many people here who know me,

I would say that the dog ate my notes.

It wasn't the dog, it was my printer

which went on the fritz.

I just am so pleased that this is taking place,

and I thank the sponsors of this occasion,

the Department of Sociology at Harvard,

and the Stone Center On Socio-Economic Inequality

at CUNY Graduate Center and the home of LIS.

It's thanks to them that this is taking place today.

Mary Waters and the department staff

have helped Janet so much in taking care of the details

in preparing for today.

Certainly, she and her staff in New York at CUNY

had plenty to do.

I thank Suzanne and Odette for all they've done,

but I have a question.

Why didn't you do something about the weather?

(audience chuckles)

Before there was LIS, before Lee was at the Department

of Sociology or at Harvard or at Washington University,

there was Social Research Incorporated

and the University of Chicago.

Lee and I met in 1956 when I went to work

in the administrative staff at SRI,

but actually; I don't know, did he make it or not?

I guess he hasn't been able to come.

I was hoping that today there was going to be another person

who had known Lee even longer, even before I did,

and that was Robert Weiss, who was a student with Lee

at the University of Chicago. (audience chuckles)

Oh, there he is!

Hey.

Hi, Bob; thanks for coming.

There's another person who was at Chicago

and who worked with Lee and me at Social Research,

and he, Gerald Handel, could not make it,

he and his wife Ruth, but their son Michael Handel

is here today, and many of you know that he was also

a graduate student at the Department of Sociology here.

Thank you, Michael, for representing our dear friends.

When we lost Lee, Janet was in Luxembourg,

Tim was in Paris with Marcy, his wife Marcy Carlson,

and their adorable little boy Finny, on sabbatical,

but that did not stop them from giving us

every bit of support they could possibly give.

They were wonderful.

Janet, with the help of Dan Cahill,

had put together the most beautiful film,

a film that recognized Lee and his work,

and was sent out to colleagues all over.

Then, they just kept doing things,

coming to see us here, Katherine and myself,

and I must say that they helped so much

in making things easier for me and for my children,

Katherine and Jon Rainwater,

and Jon's wife Susan Stephenson.

It was really great.

As Tim pointed out, when given the opportunity,

he named his professorship at Wisconsin after Lee,

and that was also terrific.

Within a few months, after Lee's death,

Janet and Tim contacted me and said they got this idea

to put together annual lectures that would memorialize Lee

and recognize his work.

Of course, I was delighted, and once they had

thought through it a bit, they started to contact people,

colleagues of Lee's and friends of Lee's,

who would make donations to holding these events,

and the response from these people was immediate

and generous, and I thank them for that.

I want to say, as I look out as this audience

and see colleagues of Lee, dear friends

from all different groups and individuals,

I'm talking about Daisy Chain, the Mermaids,

and all of these wonderful friends,

I thank you so much for being here.

But again, I want to thank the sponsors, contributors,

Robert for coming here.

Oh, I do want to say one thing about Robert.

There could be no better person

to give the first lecture than Robert.

He was there with Lee long before LIS started,

you just pointed out to me it was before, not during.

He shared data from Sweden at the very outset

and has been there for Lee and Tim, now for Jan,

and it's wonderful that he is our speaker today.

And most of all, I want to thank

Janet and Tim.

(smooches kiss)

(chuckles)

(audience applauds)

- Thank you very much Carol.

I'm Mary Waters and I'm the chair

of the Sociology Department,

and I want to welcome everybody here

on behalf of the Sociology Department.

I want to thank our fantastic staff,

especially Suzanne Ogungbadero and Odette Binder,

who have done so much work to put everything together

so nicely for us today.

I wanna just say a few words;

many of my colleagues who knew Lee and who never met Lee

are here today to join with us in remembering him

and thinking about the issues that he thought were important

with Bob's talk.

I wanted to just say a few words about Lee

and our department.

Lee taught in the Sociology Department

from 1969 'til 1992, when he retired.

He had an illustrious career, and as I thought

about Lee's career, I thought about what makes us

such a successful and, really, terrific department

to work in and to train students, and I realized

that Lee personified many of the things

and actually did many of the things before his time,

that now are spreading throughout the nation

but that harvard was one of the first to do,

and I would just mention one or two of them.

One is that our department is well known,

and we've been recruiting potential graduate students

the last few weeks, and so I've been talking up

the department, and so I've realized

that everything I've been stressing about our department,

really, Lee personifies.

One is that we train our students equally

in qualitative and quantitative research

and believe that the method is important

for asking a particular question,

and that you're not assigned to one or the other

of these things, which of course,

Lee did throughout his career.

We are an empirical department and a department

that really thinks about the real world,

and also, the implications for policy.

Many of our faculty and graduates students think about that,

and of course, Lee was a trailblazer for that.

I think about Lee's teaching, and when I first came in 1986

as a new assistant professor, I was told

by some of the other professors that Lee's course,

which was one class and on poverty and on the working class,

attracted, overwhelmingly, students who were the first

in their families to go to college,

and it was one of the few classes where they saw themselves

and they got to think about their own trajectories,

and he was really appreciated by students for that,

and we still pride ourselves

in attracting those kinds of students.

And finally, the topics that Lee devoted his life to.

Poverty, inequality, comparative research,

urban research, race, and public policy

are all things which are all very strong in our department,

among other things that we specialize in,

but that he really set an agenda

that really lives on, and lives on in our students,

and we're just very proud to have been the place

where Lee did a lot of his important research,

and we're happy to celebrate that with you today.

Thank you.

(audience applauds)

- Thank you so much.

I'm Janet Gornick, now Professor of Political Science

and Sociology at the Graduate Center

at the City University of New York.

Again, thank you, everybody, thank you for coming;

I think we've heard all this, and again,

I do want to thank especially Suzanne and Odette,

who Mary lent to me as we were getting organized.

I myself also knew Lee well, he was a big figure in my life.

I met Lee in the 1970s when I was an undergraduate here,

but I encountered him again in 1989

when I was his teaching assistant.

He was teaching a class at the Kennedy School,

where I had been affiliated and I was a PhD student here

by then, and he turned to me one day and said,

"I need to hire somebody to build a social-policy database,"

for LIS, which I had just learned about,

it was five years old at the time.

He described the job to me and I said,

"That sounds interesting."

It was a part-time research job.

We were standing at the Kennedy School

and he asked me when I could relocate.

I said, "Oh, is this job at William James?"

And he said (chuckles), "The job is in Luxembourg."

I said, "Where is Luxembourg?" (audience chuckles)

Tim tells the same story, I wasn't sure

if it was Lichtenstein or somewhere a little, anyway.

I ran home and looked on the atlas,

that's what you did in those days,

and I thought, "That looks interesting."

So I came back the next day and I said okay.

I finished my exams here and I moved to Luxembourg

where I stayed almost two years, and thus, for me,

began the rest of my life.

So that one exchange with Lee,

and then he chaired my dissertation,

and that one exchange with Lee shaped my entire career

of 27 years so far.

Lee retired, Harvard rules said he could no longer

chair the dissertation, so in stepped Chris Winship,

thank you, who I would say, how do I say this politely?

He kicked my butt, which was not Lee's style,

for those of you who knew Lee, and told me to hurry up

and finish, which I did very quickly.

So he scared the heck out of me and I finished really fast,

and I thank you, Chris, as well.

Okay, so that's that.

I have been involved with LIS all those years;

Tim was director for 23 years, I was director for 10,

and we've just recently reorganized.

Let me tell you what we're gonna do.

I'm determined to keep us on schedule.

I wanna say just a couple of words about the lecture series,

you have a program in front of you,

and as Carol mentioned, several people very quickly

and very generously donated.

We have in hand money for about eight years,

so we'll start calling you in about five years

if we get a little panicky, Tim and I'll start calling you.

But people gave very generously.

What we decided to do was alternate the lecture each year

between here, because it was Lee's home for so long

and also mine for a long time, and the Graduate Center

at the City University of New York,

where Phil Kasinitz has come today also

to wave the CUNY flag and represent

the sociology program there, which also gave.

So we'll announce in the fall the date and the new speaker,

the donors are the selection committee,

and we will certainly keep going for the next many years,

and we hope that the Rainwaters will join us

in New York each year.

Okay; the next thing we're gonna do,

we've left just 10 minutes for this.

Carol made reference to a video, and in fact,

the video was made in 2011, but of course,

what you're remembering is right after Lee died,

we recirculated it, and at that point we were tweeting

and all the new things that we can do

to put things out in circulation.

What we decided to do back in around 2008 or 2009

was to capture the story of the founding of LIS,

because it really was unusual.

It doesn't seem as unusual,

Sherri Minton is nodding, by the way,

she was a big part of our LIS life as well.

So when LIS was founded, it was an extraordinarily

revolutionary project, for everybody involved,

and it was unusual for Luxembourg,

which does not have a research community

to welcome this marvelous little project,

and there were six people who really put it together.

One of them was Lee, and one was Gaston Schaber,

and Tim, and then three others.

In any case, Dan Cahill, who's doing the video today,

and I interviewed these six people, which I think took us

to four countries and many hours,

we have about 6 1/2 hours of video,

we're only behind the camera, and we turned it

into this short story of the founding of LIS,

and so I want to show you 10 minutes of it today.

I hope it's linear enough,

I just chose a few clips the other day.

You will see Lee talking, I gave Carol a warning,

I didn't want anybody to be too surprised to see Lee up here

and speak, but Lee will tell an anecdote, actually,

about how thrilled he was with the technical side of LIS,

which Sherry Minton was really deeply part of.

I'll just say this right now, I don't think this line,

it's not in the excerpt, but it's in the longer video.

Back in the 1980s, I guess Lee was sitting in his office

writing computer code and sending it up to the server

on the 11th floor, am I right?

Is that how?

The 13th floor.

So, the way the story was told, at some point,

and this is probably apocryphal, I'm not sure,

Sherri, you can tell people later,

was at some point, what was said was,

"If he can sit in his office," on the sixth floor?

Fifth floor?

I should have prepared for this, right?

"If he could sit on the fifth floor

"and send his runs up to the 13th floor,

"why couldn't he send them to Luxembourg?"

And thus was born our remote-execution system

which made us world-famous.

So, that's what happened.

I'm gonna show you just 10 minutes

and then I'll just take three seconds to introduce Robert,

the absolute perfect choice for this lecture,

as I think you'll see, also, from this video.

- [Narrator] In the late 1970s, the American sociologist,

Lee Rainwater, became acquainted with Gaston Schaber,

a Luxembourgish psychologist.

Gaston directed a research institute in Luxembourg

known as CEPS.

He also held a faculty position at Clark University

in Western Massachusetts.

Gaston and Lee came together again

in August of 1982, at a conference on poverty

that was held at Clark University.

The Swedish sociologist Robert Erikson was also there,

as were several other European

and American social scientists.

Participants at the Clark conference discussed the idea

of creating a cross-national project

that would enable high-quality comparative research.

Those conversations led to the launch

of the Luxembourg Income Study in 1983 in Luxembourg.

Three people who were involved from its inception,

Lee Rainwater, Robert Erikson, and Tim Smeeding,

remember LIS' beginnings.

Three others who helped LIS to take root and develop,

Serge Allegrezza, Marc Cigrang, and John Coder,

also contribute their early memories.

- I knew Gaston because he had looked me up

because he had asked a colleague at Clark

who in the Cambridge area was concerned

with problems of poverty?

That was Tamara Hareven, who was a professor of history

at Clark, and she invited me to dinner to meet Gaston.

And then Gaston invited me up to Luxembourg

a couple of times, if I remmber correctly, just to talk,

or in one case, to listen in on a conference he had

of the people from the different poverty studies in Europe.

So when he presented the idea to me,

and to Marty Rhine, who was with me,

he said he would like to have a conference at Clark,

bring his people from Europe over,

and meet with some Americans who did poverty research.

- My first meeting with Lee was in the 1960s.

Lee came to Stockholm in order to use

the level-of-living study from 1968.

From that on, we had quite a lot of contact.

I had a long experience of Lee as an excellent sociologist

and a good person.

Gaston I only met at the first, what would we say, meeting

where LIS was more or less decided upon

without being formally established

here at Clark University in Massachusetts.

I didn't meet Gaston before that.

- We talked back and forth, he had his own crew

from Luxembourg, and he knew the people

who had done other poverty studies in Europe

for this European Union project.

But he didn't know anything about the work that was done

in Scandinavia on levels of living, so I told him

about Sten Johansson and Robert Erikson,

and pointed out they represented a different way

of going at this than the people he was working with,

particularly in Luxembourg, and I gave him the names

of poverty researchers from the Poverty Institute.

- Lee was the one who had the ideas of looking

at income inequality, looking at comparative studies

of income inequality to have the basis for doing that.

I think that all that, I think,

was clearly Lee's contribution.

So I think that if one should really point at somebody

who is the father of LIS, it is Lee Rainwater.

- I'll never forget the first time

I put in a whole bunch of runs, and just seeing them

roll off the printer with all of those countries,

I think maybe we had nine countries by that time,

was very, very exciting, and then the fact

that once the Internet got going, and email,

the fact that this could become a totally automatic process

was also very exciting, at least for me.

Lots of people treat those issues as,

"Well, I hope it works, and if it does work, good,"

but they weren't really interested

in the nuts and bolts of it.

That was an extra bonus in a way,

a non-social-science bonus from building the project.

- Altogether, the idea was that we were in this together,

we were trying to learn from each other,

we realized that we're providing customers with something,

and we kept, I think, to the model I set back in 1988,

which was work hard, play hard.

We were sincere about helping people

and I think that reputation has carried us to this poitn.

- In the early time when this was started,

comparisons of income data was just based

on what was produced by the governments,

and what the governments produced were,

of course, not comparable.

This was, I think, the most important aspect,

and this is the intellectual achievement.

To see both that it had to be done, and it could be done,

which I think is a piece of intellectual,

shall we say, courage.

- The great event of my life, one of them, anyway:

in September 2008, the University of Stockholm offered me,

and I received, an honorary doctorate

for the work I'd done with LIS.

I was just absolutely amazing, totally blown away.

Me, an honorary degree?

I had a wonderful time, and I'll always have fond memories

and a special place in my heart for LIS.

Lee and I are really proud of what we started,

and even prouder of what's being grown out of it.

- To be president of LIS, I must say,

was only for one period a hard work.

Otherwise, since this was a project

that was following exactly the ideas I had

about how comparative work should be done,

or rather, what the infrastructure for comparative work

should look like, in that respect, I was very happy

of being president of a nice institute.

- So, I guess in the end, we were lucky.

I think we did well because of hard work

and because of luck, and because I had Lee as a partner

and now Janet and Markus after us,

because we've had loyal employees

and because they're just really good people,

so I'm thankful.

Lee, I think at his retirement, said,

"This must be the most important thing I've done."

He thought that.

Now, this is Lee Rainwater, who's done a lot (chuckles)

of really important work, in case you didn't understand

what ghettoes were about in the '60s, '70s,

and '80s and so forth.

So, Lee could claim fame to a bunch of other stuff.

Not me.

Best thing I will ever do, have done, is LIS,

and I'm really proud of what we accomplished, again,

and where the project's going.

- It's now my pleasure to introduce Robert Erikson;

I think you can see why we were very grateful

that he agreed to give the first lecture,

'cause he's so integrally related to the project

and to Lee and so forth, and when I became

the director of LIS, 2006 to 2016,

Robert served as the board president

and a really crucial advisor for those five years.

So it's my great pleasure to welcome you.

- Okay, let me say that, as was clear from the video there,

that my first meeting with Lee, and with Carol, actually,

was around 1970.

I wonder if whether '69 was right, but never mind.

The point was that Lee came to Stockholm

because he was looking for new datasets and new ideas

how to look at inequality and poverty.

I would say as much I had followed him

during his career then, he stuck to that subject,

and wrote exactly about inequality and poverty.

This lecture is a small step behind him on inequality.

So, the idea is I should talk about social selection

in education and its consequences for mobility.

General intergenerational mobility is an immense area,

so if I should talk about it, I have to pick and select

what I should say; I can only take up a minor fraction

of the issues that come out.

What I will select, I will discuss social

rather than economic mobility, and I will emphasize

class mobility rather than status attainment,

which are on the one hand, the tradition in economics

and the other, the tradition in...

Two traditions in sociology,

and I dare to say that status attainment has been more done

here in the US, whereas class mobility has been done more

in Europe, so I thought coming here,

I should talk about class mobility.

Secondly, I will say this, that education

is the most important mechanism relating class origins

to class destinations.

That is, both for the means for children

from the more-advantaged classes to remain advantaged,

and it's a means for those from less-advantaged classes

to become better off.

So, I will then, given the importance of education,

I will start discussing how educational attainment depends

on social origins, and then discuss, too,

some aspects of the role of education in class mobility,

and where I will finally say a few words about the goal

to increase social mobility, and the possibility

to reach this goal by political measures.

In studies of the association between social background

and educational attainment, it was very early observed

that children from more advatnaged backgrounds

did, on average, perform better at school,

and also, given the performance at school,

they choose more academic lines of further education then.

This was shown by my old professor Bouwalt

who wrote his dissertation on this aspect, really, in 1947,

and Sandy Jencks over there had a paper,

I think it was in The Academic Mind,

where he also had this result.

So this was a...

Then it became, really, a major case in sociology

with the publication of the book by Raymond Boudon on...

I don't remember the name of the book,

but it was certainly on education

and the selection in education.

He called these two mechanisms,

the mechanisms that children do better at school

and therefore go further on:

the primary effect of social selection in education,

but there is also a direct effect that says

by other mechanisms than education

for the connection between social origins and destinations,

and that he called the secondary effect.

This has been established, so this is really

what we have to stick to, but it's slightly inconsequential

that the indirect effect from class origin

to class destination is called the primary effect,

and the direct effect from class origin

is called the secondary effect, but that is how it is.

It's not much we can do it.

It was really two French demographers,

Girard and Bastide, who really came up

with these two terms, but that was unknown to most of us,

because it was in a paper in French in demography.

Now, this pattern has been observed

in a very large number of countries.

In 2013, Michelle Jackson actually produced

an edited volume where you can see that pattern on this one.

We could summarize in the following way,

and I'll show it this way.

This is really a schematic picture of the whole process,

and that is, what you you have here,

you have two curves of grade-point averages

for girls, from the salariat, that is,

to upper professional and managerial fathers and mothers.

This is the grade distribution for girls

from the working class, and this is the grade distribution

for girls from the salariat.

It's a rather major difference between them.

The difference is of the size of a standard deviation

in the distribution here for girls from the working class.

I've taken just one example, given the girls

from leaving primary school at the age of 16,

and that's what it is about.

The other two curves, then, that is,

at this point, this is the point in Sweden

where the children have to divide, how to continue, right?

The crucial choice is whether you go to an academic line

in secondary school, or whether you go to a vocational line,

or perhaps just drop out.

What these two curves show,

I'll push to the right point, there, yes.

What these two curves show, they are estimates

of the probability of continuing on to the academic lines

in upper secondary school.

This curve is then the probability for girls

from the salariat, and this line is then the probability

for girls from the working class.

The difference here is rather great,

if you take somewhere in the middle here and you look,

the difference here is about 25%.

The girls from the workign class had a 25% higher chance

to go to the academic lines of upper secondary.

The combined effect

of these two effects...

You'll deal with them a little mathematically

and then you get the outcome

you increase or multiply the distribution

with the transition curve, which is, by the way,

estimated by a logistic regression.

Then, the girls from the salariat,

68% went on to acadameic lines of secondary school,

whereas 24% of the girls from the working class went on.

So it's a major difference, and it comes from both ways.

This was the point, this was what Bouwalt found,

it was what Boudon came out with,

that both effects here are operating.

You can say that the assumption behind this model

is that students, knowing their grades,

the grades are known to the students, of course,

before they decide where to go.

Knowing their grades, they have some information

about their potential, and then, on that basis,

they will decide.

But when we do it this way, we, with all probability,

underestimate the importance of choice here,

that is given by the two S-curves here.

Because if we assume that girls who, earlier in school,

decide that, "Yeah, I wanna go on to acadmics,"

they may work harder at school already,

so they may get better grades due to the choice

of continuing to upper secondary school.

So, we could try to look at another curve here.

Yes.

So, instead, in this dataset, we also have cognitive tests.

It's based on verbal, spatial, and numeric skills,

and it has all the qualities of the psychological scales

that you are used to.

So, here, we have really...

The distributions here are now the distributions

in this cognitive ability.

This is really Herrstein and Murray's bell curves,

this is precisely what it is.

And these, then, are the probabilities of the girls

choosing upper secondary school, given their grades.

Or sorry, given their cognitive ability.

And what we can see is that the difference

between the distributions of cognitive ability

and the distributions...

Sorry, the difference between the distributions

of cognitive ability are closer to each other, actually,

than the distribution of grades, which you can assume,

partly at least, is due exactly to these earlier decisions

of continuing that is more often probably taken by girls

from the salariat than from girls from the working class.

So here, we get, as you see, you get actually a larger,

in consequence, it will still give

exactly the same proportions, so it necessarily consequences

of these two distributions being closer to each other,

these will be more different.

If you look around, also, in somehwere in the middle,

the difference amounts to around 37 percentage points

between the girls from the two classes.

If you remember, it was 24% for given grades.

But in this case, the test results

are all unknown to the girls.

They are not...

So, in a sense, you can say

that the grades don't provide them with this security

or this information about their possible abilities

to continue to academics, and even if, of course,

those with very high cognitive ability

probably also got good grades, but like I said, of course,

there's a high correlation between them.

This does not provide thme the assuarance

that they will do well at upper secondary school.

And I would say, I didn't say it

but I could just, too, if we go back, it's worthwhile seeing

that at the ends of the distributions, either no one goes on

or at the top grades, everyone, both girls go on

to this academic lines of upper secondary school.

This doesn't really happen here, we got a larger difference.

Also, with the top cognitive ability,

there is not any difference of some importance.

But I could say like this:

this is an example for one group.

I could have chosen boys, I could have chosen

other cohorts, I could have chosen other countries,

other time periods, other transitions;

the picture would, in principle, be exactly like this.

It would be, of course, different;

the distributions would be different,

the transitions would be different, but the picture

would exactly stay this, and this is really the result

that we get, and that Michelle Jackson, in her book,

could show, that for all the countries in the world,

I think it was nine European nations plus the United States,

and they all come up with the same pattern, actually.

Okay.

Did I? No, okay.

Let me see, where am I.

Yeah.

Just to...

Okay, so, just to see another example,

I take the same test results, the distributions are,

of course, the same except for a few missing data,

whereas now we have the probability of getting

a university exam.

What we can see is that we get rather major difference

already, also at rather high cognitive ability,

between girls from the salariat and from the...

As I said, you can look at this in very many ways

and you can set it up.

For instance, one natural way to do it

is to look at only those who graduated

from the academic lines of upper secondary school

from where nearly all the university students come,

and you would get the same picture.

The two distributions would be pushed more together,

also the transitions would be closer,

but the picture would really look the same.

Stephen Morgan here, in the US, has pointed out

that this simple two-factor model, with primary

and secondary effects, cannot be regarded

as fully representing the cohortial mechanism...

Well, he particularly pointed out that here

in the United States, as he wrote,

race would be an important factor that should be involved

in the model.

He thought that this may not be so much of a problem

in Europe, but I think that with the increasing

ethnic diversity of the European nations,

we should certainly consider this factor as well.

But on the other hand, in spite of Morgan's critique

being quite valid, as I see it,

the model has some quite considerable heuristic value

for understanding the process, because it emphasizes

the importance of choice in educational continuation.

Particularly, you could say that it points out

that it's not only differences in ability and performance

that decides the educational careers of young people.

So I just wanted to show that was relating to choice,

which I thought would be interesting to present here,

because I never took it up in an international connection.

It was by a group of economists in Sweden in the 1990s,

and also their then-conservative government

came out and said that it may be...

The social selection in school has been an issue

that Swedish politicians have been at

since the 1940s at least, and they came out and said,

"Perhaps the social selection at school is because

"there is too little income inequality in Sweden."

And the argument is quite sensible, you see.

It says that while children

from more-advantaged backgrounds,

they will go on to university anyway,

but for the kids from the working class,

why should they take the risk of going to university

if there is not a substantial economic return to this fact?

So I think it's a sensible argument, but I still wanted

to test it, and Jon O. Jonsson and I tried to do that.

We started with the assumption that if children

from the working class are more influenced

by economic returns in their decision to continue

to higher education or not, it ought not only to concern

their choice of educational level, but it also concerns

what track to follow.

So we had access to a very large dataset

with detailed information on levels and fields of education.

And we could, for each combination of level and field,

or not each, but for many, we could set down

the average earnings of men; we took men in the ages

30 to 47, working full-time.

So for each of this educational groups,

we could apply a monetary value to it,

and the idea was then, of course, that if it was the case

that kids from the working class were more interested

in money, they ought to go for the educational combinations

or the educational tracks that gave the most money.

Then we had another dataset, of course, with younger people,

and we regressed the choice of educational track

in tertiary education, represented them by the money value

of that track on the grade-point averages from high school

on e square; we furthermore included sex,

parents' social class, parental education,

and the graduation line in academic secondary school,

which there are some differences.

So we had about 29,000 students from which we could look.

The groups from which we estimated the economic values

so to say, of the educational tracks,

I think it was 56 such groups,

and in no case we had less than 100 cases in a group

in order to have a fairly stable estimate

of the economic returns.

The first model accounted for 22% of the dependent value,

but there is one piece missing when we did this,

we thought, and that was the cost of the educational line.

So what we added to the model was the supposed length,

there was an established length of each educational track,

so we added that to the model.

We then came up to an r square of 0.45,

which is fairly decent, I would say.

In the end, then, we have it here.

I can't find the data any longer,

so I had to scan the picture of the paper

where we published it.

So what we have here is, here we have grades,

the grade-point average from the upper secondary school

before entering university; here we have this money value

of the educational tracks.

This is the managerial-and-professional class,

these are other non-manual, these are self-employed

and employers, and these are farmers and workers.

So the interesting case here is now,

those who chose the tracks paying,

were really the kids from upper-class backgrounds

or higher-class backgrounds.

You could perhaps assume that they knew how much it cost

to live the life they want to live.

So in this sense, what we could show by this paper

was that it really went against the idea

that kids from the working class were the ones

who went for the money when choosing education,

and I can, to my satisfaction here, say

that I never heard the argument mentioned

after this paper, actually.

(audience chuckles)

But why may it be that students

from more-advantaged backgrounds

choose the high-paying tracks, apart from this idea?

There is an idea from an excellent paper

by two American sociologists;

Keller and Zavalloni had a paper in Social Forces, 1964.

No, damn it, that was the wrong way; here we are.

This is a very schematic picture of their idea.

Here we have educational level, here we have

the subjective value of choosing that education,

and then we have two persons, say, two girls,

with different social background.

For both of them, the subjective value of more education

increases with the educational level.

But, and this was the idea by Keller and Zavalloni,

the subjective value of additional education

is less when you are past your aspiration level.

You can think of it like this, that if you compare

the assumed subjective value of becoming a certified nurse

for the daughter of a supermarket cashier

and for a physician, it's rather probable

that they value this education differently.

This, of course, is here.

At this point where, I suppose, the aspiration level

of the girl, say, from the workign class,

after that, it increases; still, more education

is still valuable, but the increase is not as sharp,

and this only happens for the other girl

when she reaches her aspiration level here,

and then, the assumption is that these two go on

where the slope is the same.

That is to say, we assume the same process,

and what is different is the situation

that defines the aspiration of the girls.

I think was, in my view, a very important paper

because at that time, it was the idea that the working class

didn't actually value higher education,

but here they assumed that the valuation is the same.

It's only the situation that differs.

I think it's a paper that could have been observed

more than it has, I think.

And the consequences, of course,

the value of a certain education is higher

for children from more-advantaged backgrounds.

So they have more reason to choose this type of education.

Okay, more generally, if we take the two mechanisms here,

you can say that differences in performance,

the primary effect, can be assumed to depend

on a combined effect of nature and nurture.

It's probable that kids from advataged backgrounds

from the start obtained relatively good cogintive

and non-cognitive skills, on the basis of the interaction

between genetics and environment, and this interaction,

I will say, I have great difficulties with these people

that come out and say that, "It's 80% that is genes,"

or, "It's 60% that is genes."

It's an interaction, and it starts

from the conception and onwards.

But I mean, parents with higher education

use a more elaborate vocabulary, which is probably part

of the explanation that their children, on average,

do clearly better on verbal tests, already,

at the age of three.

Children from the salariat, that they get

the cognitive advantage already at an early age,

of course, is to their benefit when they continue.

This is Heckman's idea of skill begets skill.

Furthermore, for this, children with salariat parents have,

presumably, conditions at home: more space, more books

that is to their advantage, leading to a better performance

to the primary effect.

To account for difference in choice

due the secondary effects, Jan O. Jonsson and I suggested

a very simple model.

We said that we have to consider the benefits

of the education, we should consider the cost

of the education, and we have to consider

the probability of success.

With some fiddling you come to a very simple model here,

saying the value or the utility

of choosing a certain education is dependent on the benefits

minus the costs, but the benefits are partly dependent,

they must be valued according to the probability

of succeeding in the education.

The idea of this model, it's a very simple thing,

and it's, again, a heuristic model,

because if you assume that these benefits in cost

are estimated as subjective values, you get difficult

if you wanna test it, but the point is

what we should look at, trying to understand

the educational choice of children from different classes.

It's a rather good argument that all three factors,

actually, are to the advantage of children

from higher origins.

They get more benefits, as we saw, for instance,

with the Keller-and-Zavalloni model,

they can take the costs much easier of higher education,

because they have the support from their parents,

or they can rely on the support from their parents,

I could say.

They also probably have a hgher probability of succeeding,

because of getting better guidance

from their parents, et cetera.

Breen and Goldthorpe has another testable model,

just looking at avoidance of downward social mobility

as important to avoid.

The avoidance of downward social mobility

will lead working-class kids go into vocational education

because that will offer them a good job,

and they don't run into the risk of if they go

into academic studies, they don't succeed,

the option of a vocational career

may not be open any longer.

So in that sense, this is...

And Jan and I also had some ideas in our paper

on this idea.

Breen and Goldthorpe, central in their model

is risk aversion, exactly this:

you avoid the risk of downward mobility.

The interesting case here, I think, is

both Keller and Zavalloni, and Breen and Goldthorpe, here,

are actually in line with Kahneman and Tversky

in their prospect theory, because what they all say

is that there are differences.

A loss like downward mobility weighs heavier than gain

in terms of...

And the Keller and Zavalloni, I think, is a very...

Kahneman and Tversky ought to have referred

to them, actually.

Okay.

So, just to say that...

What about, then, social mobility?

The simplest understanding of intergenerational

social mobility is the proportion of children who are

in another social class than their parents.

Children who are higher up have been upwardly mobile,

children who are further down have been downwardly mobile.

The rate of absolute mobility is, to a very large extent,

determined by the change of the social structure.

That is to say, in the earlier part of the previous century,

when industrial work increased

and work in farming decreased, children of farmers

and farm workers, with necessity, had to move

to industrial work or some other work,

but they had to leave their origin class,

which, of course, leads also then to absolute moility.

The same on what has been called, in some cases,

the golden age of social mobility in the '50s and the '60s,

when the upper salariat increased very quickly,

which opened more room at the top,

as some British dramatic wrote about it.

But what happens now is,

if, as it seems now, the social structure is changing less,

we seem to get a larger proportion

of low-skilled service jobs.

Absolute mobility will probably decrease,

and downward class mobility will probably, or may increase,

I could say.

So, differences between the distributions

of origin and destination are a major determinant

of absolute mobility.

The other major factor is social fluidity.

It refers to the inherent association

between the origin classes and the destination classes.

We can measure it so it's not dependent

on differences between the distributions

of origin and destination.

So you can say social fluidity refers

to an individual's probability of reaching one position

in the class structure rather than another,

in relation to the corresponding probabilities

of individuals from other social origins.

This relation is very close to a precise definition

of inequality or opportunity, I would say.

Given the central role of education for the association

between origins and destination,

much interest has been devoted

to what is called the OED triangle.

You have, again, an indirect effect,

origin over education over to destination,

and you have a direct effect, which it says

is via other mechanisms than education

that leads from the origin class and the destination.

It can be seen as only a fragment

of Blau and Duncan's path model, of course,

but I think even if it's a simple thing,

much insight can actually be gained from it,

in this simple three-way association.

The interesting case is that it has been,

from time to time, shown there is an interaction

in this three-way association.

Hout, in a very influential paper,

found that an observed increase in fluidity

in the United States could be accounted for

by increasing number of children or young people

going to university, because the association

between the origin class and the destination class is lower

among those with university education,

and Mike Hout even suggested

that there's no association at all.

I don't believe that.

It may have been in his data,

but there is some problems with that.

Then, the increasing numbers with university education

accounted for a decrease in class mobility,

or rather, he looked, I think, if I remember right,

on status attainment, but never mind,

the mechanisms are, of course, very similar.

This has been shown for several countries.

Florencia Torche, in some very, I think, good papers,

could confirm the association between parental status

and men's status, that it decreases

with increasing levels of education.

But she also found that it doesn't go all the way through,

that is to say, the association between origin class

and destination class was higher among those

with advanced degrees, as compared to those

with bachelor degrees, and this is an intersting case,

because it gives some support to an idea by Sam Lucas

about maximally maintaining equality.

I would interpret it and say that under competition,

children and parents from more-advantaged backgrounds

realize that they have to use their resources

and move up in the educational ladder.

This is part of the problem with much of this research;

the question is, does education mean the same?

When it was when I went to university, I think we were

about 5% and 10% of a cohort,

and does then university education mean the same

as when the present cohort, they are 30%,

or even more than 30% of the cohort goes to university,

which makes a major difference.

So going on here, I would say what about Sweden then?

I have some data from Swedish register data

for cohorts born between '48 and '72,

and it's the whole Swedish population, so it refers

to about two million men and women here.

Here you have exactly a way of looking at the same results.

I put the data in five cross-cohorts,

born '48 to '52, and here, the last one, '68 to '72,

and then you have the association

between origin class and destination class

for those with only basic education,

for those with lower secondary education,

for those with academic secondary education

and lower tertiary, we have those with tertiary education,

and then with long tertiary education.

I did this in order to try to replicate Torche's study.

What we see here is we find exactly the same basic pattern

as in the United States: the less education,

the higher is the association

between origin and destination.

We don't really find the difference between advanced degrees

and degrees on bachelor level, they are intermingled here.

What we see here is, yeah, there is some change over time,

which is, in this, now when we talk here,

not so important, I think.

So, a few words about the model.

It's based on what is called the uniform-difference model

that John Goldthorpe and I developed when we were looking

at social mobility.

It says, like this, that if you compare

the association in each of the 25 tables here

with one of them, this is then the association

among men with only basic education

born in the first cohort.

The point is here that we assume the same basic pattern

of interaction, between origins and destination,

but the strength may differ.

To be precise, if you take an odds ratio in one table

and relate it to the similar odds ratio in another table,

the ratio between these two odds ratios

will be exactly the ratio given

by the parameter values here.

I'm lying a little when I say that these are men,

because the model also includes women.

I put the women in the same, so in principle,

you have 50, actually.

And then it looks like this, and the reason

why I put the women in there was, of course,

that I was curious about what you see here,

that the association is much lower among women

than it is among men.

This was especially the case in the earlier period,

where fewer women went to the labor market,

and it may have been that it was not so important

whether you had this job or that job,

which, apparently, then changed over time.

There's another interesting case with the women,

and that is that here, Torche's result appears, again.

That is to say, okay, we have the basic education women,

we have those with lower secondary, upper secondary

or lower tertiary, then we have those on the bachelor level

and those with advanced degrees.

Actually, there, again, the association is higher.

So, it's an exact replication of Torche's result, actually,

that appears here for women.

It's also worthwhile observing the difference

between women with only basic education,

because apparently, here, I would say

the interpretation is that women with only basic education,

coming from the working class, have very little options

on the labor market.

Okay.

Yeah.

But is it obvious that this is the best way to look at it?

Should we follow Hout in doing this?

As we said, there is a three-way interaction,

so you could look at the interaction some other way.

So why not look at it, what is the association

between education and class, given origin?

In principle, and then it looks like this.

Again, we have a pattern that is similar,

that is to say, it's in principle the same model,

so here you have the group...

Where am I?

What happened?

Okay.

There we are.

We have the group that is from the working class

in the first cohort, and then you have

the skilled working class, you have intermediate occupations

and self-employed, we have the lower, non-manual,

and we have the professional and managerial origins.

And then we could see a very stable pattern,

that the higher the class origin,

the lower is the association between education

and destination class.

This is important.

Let me say that it's not the model that brings out the data

or behaves so nicely, it's because the large sample size,

I would say.

What we can say here is that what this means

is that it's an intersting case.

It's a clear case that children from...

Okay, I can say children.

These are women and it's exactly the same pattern.

What we can say, again, was the interest to have women

in the same model with men because you can see originally,

the association between education and class was much higher

for women than for men, but it decreased much quicker,

so here, is really they are very close,

on the same level or less.

But what we see here, that children from higher origins,

they have more options in choosing jobs based on education,

which is, I think, an important interest to look at.

We could say that

in modernization theory, say like what Treiman wrote

a paper on 1970, right?

Which was a very good paper, actually.

But he came up with this idea that given the development,

and of course, it's the whole functional theory

that is behind it, actually, that given the development

of industrial and post-industrial societies,

competition increases all the time,

which pushes...

Skills and competence will become more important,

and other factors of workers will become less important

in allocation to jobs on the labor market.

And what we can see here is that Sweden doesn't fit

to that pattern, really.

Because one of the things that should happen

is exactly this, this should absolutely not happen

that you can have a difference

in the more education you have, given the origin,

you have more options.

Or, sorry, given the origin, the association

between education and destination actually become weaker,

and this will happen if it's the case

that the upper managerial class increases in size.

If we take the same argument as Hout did

with regard to the association between origin class

and destination, the association between education

and class destinations will decrease, actaully.

Which is an intersting case.

Okay, I realize that I, as always, talk too much.

I would like to end by saying a few words

about whether the rate of social mobility

is responsive to politics.

I would say like this, that politicians

in several countries, including my own, talk very much

about they have to increase social mobility,

and they have to take measures to increase social mobility.

I saw that the British government has now come up,

apparently, with some lot of things with this purpose.

But the question is, can social mobility really increase

as an effect of political action?

By intended political action?

My answer is, on the overall, no.

Upward social mobility, and that is what politicians have

in mind; they don't want to tell their electorate

that, "We want to increase social mobility

"so your kids would have a worse chance

"in the labor market."

It actually happened in a meeting in Britain,

and the then-minister of education,

this was in the previous government,

in the conservative government, came up with a big issue

that they would increase social mobility,

and after a while, I couldn't keep quiet.

I asked him, "How shall you tell your electorate

"who is in the upper part of the social structure,

"how can you go and tell them that, 'Politics work hard

"'that your children shouldn't do as well as you do,

"'or have done.'"

And I got an answer of about 15 minutes that said nothing.

It was a remarkable event, actually.

But okay, influencing social mobility.

First of all, and this is, as I said,

what we observe, of course, this idea of social...

Sorry.

Of social...

Good heavens.

What is it called?

Oh, never mind; the association.

The absolute mobility is, of course, what is observed

and seen, and the issue of what really pushes

the absolute mobility is changes in the social structure,

and the question is, is it really the case that,

with political action, where you can really change this

in order to improve social mobility?

It seems a rather weird idea.

What is, then, the option...

Instead of going on the social selection, or rather,

if you want to instead go on the other major factor

behind social mobility, social fluidity,

to what extent can we influence social fluidity

by political action?

I think the point with the distinction

between primary and secondary effects study,

it seems essential for approaching this question.

Jackson and Jonsson, in this volume

edited by Michelle Jackson, comparing European countries,

they found that there were rather small differences

in the importance of primary effects,

which suggests that this is rather basic

in the selection process; exactly the issues

that goes for why children from more-advantaged classes

do better at school, or more or less the same,

are probably very difficult to influence.

The result will be that should we, by politics,

influence social mobility, we have to go

and try to do it via education, really.

In order to influence social fluidity.

So, what Jackson and Jonsson's result suggests is this.

The question is, to what extent, if we think

of the three factors that Jan and I suggested,

benefits, costs, and probability of success,

you can say that benefits are probably very difficult to...

That they should differ by social class.

The probability of success is probably

also very difficult to influence.

So the only thing left is the cost,

and that seems to be a possibility.

The costs of going to higher education is fairly high,

so if you reduce that cost, that ought to have an effect

on social selection in education.

I'm not so certain.

I think that

children, if under increased competition

for higher education, exactly what Torche then found,

is that okay, under these considerations, still,

children must try to keep their advantage,

and how do they do it?

They continue further up in the educational system.

I think very little happens.

So I would say, I think it's rather improbable

that politicians can find a way to make a major

or even minor effect on social mobility.

Social mobility may change, that I'm not saying,

but the question of intentional political action,

I'm not so certain about.

I would say it like this.

The goal of increased social mobility seems difficult

to reach, and it would take a generation

for it to be realized.

If the aim is to reduce inequality,

a more trafficable way leading to immediate results

would be to reduce inequality of results.

Thank you.

(audience applauds)

- [Janet] Thank you, Robert, you can stay right there.

- I took too long, as always.

- That was a depressing ending, I might add.

(audience chuckles) Questions?

We have about 10 minutes, maybe we could take

a couple of questions.

Let me just mention something I think we said:

we have a reception outside, everyone is of course invited

and that's supposed to be about 6:15 to 7:15,

so I'm gonna push us out in just a few minutes,

but any questions wanna be asked?

Either from the audience or from the microphone over here?

- So, the level of association is lower

on a long tertiary level than on the earlier levels.

So does that, to some extent, moderate your last comment

that even if education saturates,

people would still find ways to...?

- [Robert] I didn't get the question, sorry.

I have to listen a little closer.

- Right.

In your concluding remark, you used Torche's finding.

But in Torche's finding,

even on long-tertiary-level education,

she found that the association between family background

and attainment resurged.

But even after it increased from the level,

it's still lower.

- Yeah, no, of course.

Exactly, okay.

It's clearly the case you will still have this association,

but the point is that, I think there are good arguments

believing that

among those with less education,

what you could say is that in those cases,

the direct effect,

the direct effect of class background

on class destination comes in,

that is, other mechanisms.

The obvious example is, really, which is slightly different,

and that is the self-employed, because the association

between the origin class and the destination class,

for that, amongst those who come from self-employment,

education is much less important,

because there are other factors.

Particularly, of course, if they stay in self-employment,

other factors become more important,

for at least many types of jobs.

But you are right, it still is a considerable difference.

- Right, so does that modify your final argument

that expanding education--

- Well, the final argument is

what should the politicians do?

- So given that, why isn't expanding education a way

to increase intergenerational mobility?

- To?

- Increase intergenerational mobility.

- Let's put it this way, the argument is really like this,

that there are very strong countervailing factors.

The interests of both parents and children

to stay in good conditions in an advantaged position

is such that resources will be brought into the model.

It seems to me, it's very difficult on the political side

to find means where you can get by this basic fact,

and precisely the fact that if now, the kid,

and this is the interesting case where this result

would hold origin constant and look at the association

between education and class destination,

and you'll find that with higher origin,

you have a lower association, which means that kids

from higher origins have other means

to get into good positions.

And all these things are...

As long as we have...

Jones, Hauser, and Featherman suggested that

what we here call social fluidity will be about the same

in nations based on a market system

and based on nuclear families, and I think this is

precisely what is going on here.

These two major institutions in societies

will form the process.

- [Janet] I see another comment over here.

Well, presumably a question, but something tells me

it's a comment.

(audience chuckles)

- Yes, ma'am.

Robert.

I would say, I think, the same thing a little differently.

- Okay.

- Well-educated parents, they have one or two children.

They invest everything in them.

They know how to get through the school system.

Their kids never worry about whether they can afford

to go to school or not, so the C thing disappears,

and then they have connections, their business...

The big thing is how do you tell a parent

that they can't do everything that they can

for their children?

That is the major problem.

That is the big class divide.

Are you gonna be a politician who's gonna say,

"Okay, who's out there with their smart little kid?"

And two parents and worked real hard and got the kid

in Harvard, that, "You, ump, no no!

"You can't do everything you can for him.

"You can't do this and you can't;" of course you can.

And that's the major problem, I think.

- I agree.

- Well, good!

(audience laughs)

Education, as it seems to me, is a by-product.

- But the important point is, still,

you have in a large number of countries,

the politicians come out and say,

"We should increase social mobility."

I suppose it's based on the idea that inequality of results

is not so important if there is a high degree

of equality of opportunity.

But I think--

- No, where you are now is where Solow,

that economist, is, and Piketty and a lot others:

unless you get rid of the inequality to start with,

you're gonna have a real hard time working your way

through a social system to get there.

Thank you, Robert.

- [Janet] Do we have one last question?

I saw a couple of other emphatic nodding faces, hands.

Sandy, can we pull you down here, and we're gonna give you

the last question.

- So you said, rightly, that a big determinant of mobility

is the changing distribution of jobs, or occupations.

Now, that suggests that if the political class wants

to change the distribution, it can change

the distribution of jobs.

It obviously can't change what people do,

because they're not smart enough to do that.

Employers have to do that, but they can change

what people are paid, and what they get to keep,

and if you compress the distribution of the monetary part,

given that you can't compress the distribution

of anything else, then you will have the effect

that the set of jobs that are available

to the next generation are either more equal,

or, in the case of the United States lately,

less equal than the jobs that were available

in a previous generation, and you will therefore have

either more or less mobility of a certain kind,

because you've changed that distribution of payoffs.

Now, that won't have any effect at all

on the rank order of mobility, people will still be moving

up and down, just like in the diagrams,

but what they think has happened to them

will change a lot, I think.

- That could be.

That could be.

I think, still...

Yeah.

Yeah, it may be.

This is an interesting case.

To what extent what people see is exactly absolute mobility?

This idea of the association is something

the sociologists thought up in their minds

and is still hardly out to them.

But no, okay.

The interesting case was that when you say

they compress the income distribution,

but the interesting case, what as I showed before,

the economists in Sweden thought

that they should increase income inequality.

- It is my sad duty to, it's not so sad,

to bring us to a close.

Robert, thank you so much.

(audience applauds)

Thank you.

- [Robert] Thank you for being invited.

- Thank you to the Rainwaters for coming,

and Tim, for all your energy over so many years,

and to so many people in the room here.

Next year, this event will be at the City University

of New York, as I've said, Phil will take Mary's role.

I want you to know, speaking of this topic,

that there was just a big study that came out

by Raj Chetty, which we're all very proud of at CUNY

because he looked at the 10 campuses in this country

that created the most social mobility,

the most likely that students entered

from a disadvantaged background,

and then they themselves had household income

in the top quintile, and six of those 10 colleges

were ours at CUNY, so we were very proud of that.

So that's just a little reason to tell you

why you should all come next year,

because if you're interested in social mobility,

that's our business, and we wanna show off CUNY.

I'm a big CUNY patriot, I'm also a Harvard patriot.

There's a lot more money here than there,

so anyway, there you go.

Thank you so much to everybody,

and please join us at the reception.

(audience applauds)

(pensive, midtempo music)

For more infomation >> Social Selection in Education and its Consequences for Mobility - Duration: 1:40:30.

-------------------------------------------

Message for your night 31 May - Duration: 0:56.

For more infomation >> Message for your night 31 May - Duration: 0:56.

-------------------------------------------

Celebrity Big Brother hell for Megan McKenna as Ex On The Beach boyfriend signs up - Duration: 3:00.

Celebrity Big Brother hell for Megan McKenna as Ex On The Beach boyfriend signs up

And one person who might not want to watch the new series of the hit Channel 5 show is Megan McKenna.

**FIRST CELEBRITY BIG BROTHER 2017 STAR REVEALED ** The TOWIE beautys ex Pete Wicks has previously been linked to the upcoming series of the show.

However, it appears to be double trouble for the brunette bombshell as her Ex On The Beach co-star and ex-boyfriend Jordan Davies has now reportedly signed on the dotted line for the series.

Jordan, 25, is set to enter the CBB house and spill all the secrets of his relationship with the reality TV babe.

A source told The Sun: Jordan is going to reveal all the secrets of his relationship with Megan and hold nothing back.

The show turned her into reality TV gold and viewers cant get enough of anything about her – even her ex. Its why the bosses wanted Jordan – it will make for explosive television..

After Megan took part in the series her career went on to reach new highs, she has made mega money, became a series regular in TOWIE and is set to open her own restaurant.

The insider claims Megan will be mortified by Jordans signing on for the show, as shes a private person and her ex has become a thing of the past for a reason.

They added: Shes come a long way since she was with him and has become a successful business woman so she wont want people to focus on someone from her past..

To make matters worse, Jordan could come face-to-face with Megans recent other high-profile ex, Pete Wicks. The decision was said to be no brainer for Pete, as he wants a break from TOWIE and show bosses are reportedly offering big money.

It comes as Daily Star Online exclusively revealed the first female housemate to sign for CBB was Real Housewives of Beverly Hills bombshell Brandi Glanville.

For more infomation >> Celebrity Big Brother hell for Megan McKenna as Ex On The Beach boyfriend signs up - Duration: 3:00.

-------------------------------------------

Tourettes Guy Saying BUTT FUCK For 10 Minutes Straight - Duration: 10:06.

BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK BUTT FUCK

For more infomation >> Tourettes Guy Saying BUTT FUCK For 10 Minutes Straight - Duration: 10:06.

-------------------------------------------

Class in session: Spelling bee time for WDSU morning team - Duration: 2:30.

IN D.C. FOR THE

SPELLING BEE

GOOD LUCK TO ALL OF YOU OFF.

WHITTLESEY HOUSE -- GOOD LUCK TO

ALL YALL.

WE WILL SEE HOW SMART YOU ALL

ARE.

THE FIRST WORD, THIS WAS THE

WINNING WORD WHICH WAS DEFINED

AS SOCIAL RELATIONS BASED ON

IMPERSONAL TIES, DUTY TO A

SOCIETY OR ORGANIZATION.

THE WORD IS GESELLSCHAFT.

GESELLSCHAFT IS THE WORD YOU

WILL SPELL.

A LITTLE OFF.

YOU SPELLED IT LIKE GISELE

LUNCHEON.

CHARLES: THIS WILL BE YOUR

CHANCE.

THIS IS ANOTHER WINNING WORD

FROM 1951.

>> SAY IT IN A SENTENCE.

THE WORD IS INSUFFICIENT.

>>ENSUITIEN.

CHARLES: ALMOST.

OF THE NATIONAL SPELLING BEE,

IN HONOR GOOGLE HAS PULLED THE

MOST MISSPELLED WORDS FROM EACH

STATE.

CHECK THIS OUT, APPARENTLY

LOUISIANIANS CAN'T SPELL

GIRAFFE.

>> SERIOUSLY?

CHARLES: IN MISSISSIPPI IT'S

M

NANNY.

TEXAS IS MAINTENANCE, AND

PENNSYLVANIA IS SAUERKRAUT.

NANNY?

>>NANNIE?

CHARLES: YOU ARE WRONG.

IT IS A Y.

Không có nhận xét nào:

Đăng nhận xét